Senin, 30 Desember 2013

Operational Excellence Handbook: A Must Have for Those Embarking On a Journey of Transformation and Continuous Improvement,

Operational Excellence Handbook: A Must Have for Those Embarking On a Journey of Transformation and Continuous Improvement, by Rod Baxter

It is not secret when connecting the composing abilities to reading. Reviewing Operational Excellence Handbook: A Must Have For Those Embarking On A Journey Of Transformation And Continuous Improvement, By Rod Baxter will certainly make you get more resources as well as resources. It is a manner in which can improve how you overlook and understand the life. By reading this Operational Excellence Handbook: A Must Have For Those Embarking On A Journey Of Transformation And Continuous Improvement, By Rod Baxter, you could greater than exactly what you get from other publication Operational Excellence Handbook: A Must Have For Those Embarking On A Journey Of Transformation And Continuous Improvement, By Rod Baxter This is a widely known publication that is released from renowned author. Seen form the author, it can be relied on that this book Operational Excellence Handbook: A Must Have For Those Embarking On A Journey Of Transformation And Continuous Improvement, By Rod Baxter will certainly give numerous inspirations, regarding the life and encounter and also every little thing within.

Operational Excellence Handbook: A Must Have for Those Embarking On a Journey of Transformation and Continuous Improvement, by Rod Baxter

Operational Excellence Handbook: A Must Have for Those Embarking On a Journey of Transformation and Continuous Improvement, by Rod Baxter



Operational Excellence Handbook: A Must Have for Those Embarking On a Journey of Transformation and Continuous Improvement, by Rod Baxter

PDF Ebook Download : Operational Excellence Handbook: A Must Have for Those Embarking On a Journey of Transformation and Continuous Improvement, by Rod Baxter

Operational Excellence Handbook is designed for leaders and practitioners wishing to transform their organizations through strategy and culture, and through the application of operational excellence approaches, methodologies, processes, and tools. The handbook contains 70 chapters organized in five sections describing strategy, culture, methodologies, project management, and tools that are helpful to create immediate and sustainable value for your organization. As you travel on your value generation journey, you will wish to select the appropriate approach, methodologies, and tools – based on your organization’s current situation, future strategies and goals, resource availability and limitations, as well as urgency and schedule needs – that will provide immediate value. With the purchase of this handbook, the reader has access to a file containing all templates referenced in the eBook.

Operational Excellence Handbook: A Must Have for Those Embarking On a Journey of Transformation and Continuous Improvement, by Rod Baxter

  • Amazon Sales Rank: #790999 in eBooks
  • Published on: 2015-09-24
  • Released on: 2015-09-24
  • Format: Kindle eBook
Operational Excellence Handbook: A Must Have for Those Embarking On a Journey of Transformation and Continuous Improvement, by Rod Baxter

From the Inside Flap This Operational Excellence Handbook contains 70 chapters organized in five sections describing strategy, culture, methodologies, project management, and tools that are helpful to create immediate and sustainable value for your organization. To achieve a communications- and team-based culture of continuous improvement, this handbook is appropriate for organizations' leaders and practitioners alike. As you travel on your value generation journey, you will wish to select the appropriate approach, methodologies, and tools - based on your organization's current situation, future strategies and goals, resource availability and limitations, as well as urgency and schedule needs - that will provide immediate value. This handbook is the culmination of thirty-five years of experience in the practical application of project management, quality management, continuous improvement, transformation, and operational excellence. It is intended to provide you with information to help you determine the appropriate approach, process, methodology, and tools that are right for you and your organization, and how to apply them based on your specific needs. It's important to note that not all organizations are on the same value generation journey. Likely the starting point and the destination differ by organization. One organization's journey may be focused on full-scale transformation; another organization's continuous improvement efforts may be specific to cost reduction and quality improvement. Many of the tools and approaches described in this handbook may be used alone or together as an overall approach to your value generation journey. The speed and magnitude of results will vary based on the organization's complexity and commitment to change. Regardless of your value generation journey's path, appropriate attention to commitment, discipline, and rigor must be given to the five key elements of operational excellence. Strategic Approach + Cultural Leadership + Methodology + Project Management + Tools = Operational Excellence

From the Back Cover You are holding a handbook designed for leaders and practitioners wishing to transform their organizations through strategy and culture, and through the application of operational excellence approaches, methodologies, processes, and tools.   This book will provide you with thought and guidance on: · Strategic Approaches · Cultural Leadership · Practices and Methodologies · Project Management · Tool Selection and Use

About the Author Rod Baxter, author of Operational Excellence Handbook, Strategy Driven for Success Handbook, Project Management for Success Handbook, Problem Solving for Success Handbook, and Workshop Facilitation for Success Handbook, is principal and cofounder of Value Generation Partners, headquartered in Naples, FL. In his thirty-year career, he has led operational excellence and continuous improvement efforts for organizations such as ACI Worldwide, Diebold, The Hoover Company, The Timken Company, GOJO Industries, Florida Gulf Coast University, and Kent State University. Through these experiences, he traveled around the globe, facilitating teams in China, Singapore, UAE, India, Japan, Korea, Mexico, United Kingdom, France, Germany, and Poland. As a Value Generation Partners principal, Rod is the subject matter expert, facilitating its Operational Excellence training, consulting, coaching, and project mentoring.   Rod holds a bachelors of science degree from Kent State University and an MBA from the University of Akron, and has earned the following professional certifications:   Certifications include: ▪ Project Management Professional from the Project Management Institute ▪ New Product Development Professional from the Product Development and Management Association ▪ Lean Six Sigma Master Black Belt from the International Society for Six Sigma Professionals ▪ Six Sigma Black Belt from the American Society for Quality ▪ Manager of Operational Excellence from the American Society for Quality   Rod is a distinguished alumni of Kent State University's College of Technology, published guest writer to Quality Progress magazine, and has served as a member of the board of examiners for Ohio Award for Excellence and Malcolm Baldrige National Quality Award.


Operational Excellence Handbook: A Must Have for Those Embarking On a Journey of Transformation and Continuous Improvement, by Rod Baxter

Where to Download Operational Excellence Handbook: A Must Have for Those Embarking On a Journey of Transformation and Continuous Improvement, by Rod Baxter

Most helpful customer reviews

0 of 0 people found the following review helpful. Not bad for the price. By David E. The book is more a glossary than a handbook. The author's 70 topics are touched on very superficially with just enough of an introduction to make the reader want to learn more about them - by consulting other resources. Many of the topics in this book are covered more adequately in Nancy Tague's The Quality Toolbox, but the ones that Tague doesn't cover are nicely introduced here. There is definitely value in this book, but I think I would have sent it back if it had cost much more than it did. If you haven't had any other introduction to quality or business management tools, this could be a good start. Or, find a copy of the table of contents and do a google search to learn just as much, if not more. If you're a serious practitioner or student of the subject, pay the price for something meatier like Tague or Breyfogle.

See all 1 customer reviews... Operational Excellence Handbook: A Must Have for Those Embarking On a Journey of Transformation and Continuous Improvement, by Rod Baxter


Operational Excellence Handbook: A Must Have for Those Embarking On a Journey of Transformation and Continuous Improvement, by Rod Baxter PDF
Operational Excellence Handbook: A Must Have for Those Embarking On a Journey of Transformation and Continuous Improvement, by Rod Baxter iBooks
Operational Excellence Handbook: A Must Have for Those Embarking On a Journey of Transformation and Continuous Improvement, by Rod Baxter ePub
Operational Excellence Handbook: A Must Have for Those Embarking On a Journey of Transformation and Continuous Improvement, by Rod Baxter rtf
Operational Excellence Handbook: A Must Have for Those Embarking On a Journey of Transformation and Continuous Improvement, by Rod Baxter AZW
Operational Excellence Handbook: A Must Have for Those Embarking On a Journey of Transformation and Continuous Improvement, by Rod Baxter Kindle

Operational Excellence Handbook: A Must Have for Those Embarking On a Journey of Transformation and Continuous Improvement, by Rod Baxter

Operational Excellence Handbook: A Must Have for Those Embarking On a Journey of Transformation and Continuous Improvement, by Rod Baxter

Operational Excellence Handbook: A Must Have for Those Embarking On a Journey of Transformation and Continuous Improvement, by Rod Baxter
Operational Excellence Handbook: A Must Have for Those Embarking On a Journey of Transformation and Continuous Improvement, by Rod Baxter

Kamis, 26 Desember 2013

Sires and Sons: The Story of Hubbard's Regiment, by Trevor P. Wardlaw

Sires and Sons: The Story of Hubbard's Regiment, by Trevor P. Wardlaw

Exactly what should you believe more? Time to get this Sires And Sons: The Story Of Hubbard's Regiment, By Trevor P. Wardlaw It is very easy after that. You can only rest as well as remain in your location to get this book Sires And Sons: The Story Of Hubbard's Regiment, By Trevor P. Wardlaw Why? It is on-line publication establishment that provide many collections of the referred publications. So, merely with internet link, you can appreciate downloading this publication Sires And Sons: The Story Of Hubbard's Regiment, By Trevor P. Wardlaw and also varieties of books that are looked for now. By checking out the web link page download that we have actually supplied, the book Sires And Sons: The Story Of Hubbard's Regiment, By Trevor P. Wardlaw that you refer a lot can be found. Just save the asked for publication downloaded and install and after that you could delight in guide to review every single time and place you really want.

Sires and Sons: The Story of Hubbard's Regiment, by Trevor P. Wardlaw

Sires and Sons: The Story of Hubbard's Regiment, by Trevor P. Wardlaw



Sires and Sons: The Story of Hubbard's Regiment, by Trevor P. Wardlaw

PDF Ebook Download : Sires and Sons: The Story of Hubbard's Regiment, by Trevor P. Wardlaw

From the unbridled lands of East Texas, tenacious men with diverse backgrounds came together to form the Twenty-Second Texas Infantry. Also known as Hubbard’s regiment, families synonymous with the Texas Revolution joined the ranks of politicians, attorneys, farmers, and teachers. Many championed Southern values whereas some campaigned for Northern agendas. Yet, most were Texan by choice and they sought to defend their homes. The regiment’s stories of triumph and sorrow intertwined with American history as the men drudged across the unforgiving lands west of the Mississippi River. They fought in the bloody encounters of Fort DeRussy, Mansfield, Pleasant Hill, and Jenkins’ Ferry as life-threatening diseases complicated their service. Their ambitious marches forever tied them to the story of Texas during the Civil War.

Sires and Sons: The Story of Hubbard's Regiment, by Trevor P. Wardlaw

  • Amazon Sales Rank: #1200141 in Books
  • Published on: 2015-05-28
  • Original language: English
  • Number of items: 1
  • Dimensions: 9.00" h x .78" w x 6.00" l, 1.01 pounds
  • Binding: Paperback
  • 312 pages
Sires and Sons: The Story of Hubbard's Regiment, by Trevor P. Wardlaw

About the Author Trevor P. Wardlaw is a native Texan. He was born in Waco, Texas, yet he spent much of his childhood in South Bend, Indiana, and New York City. A graduate of Baylor University, he has been married for over two decades and is the proud father of three children. The family lives in Central Texas where Mr. Wardlaw works as an Investment Advisor Representative.


Sires and Sons: The Story of Hubbard's Regiment, by Trevor P. Wardlaw

Where to Download Sires and Sons: The Story of Hubbard's Regiment, by Trevor P. Wardlaw

Most helpful customer reviews

3 of 3 people found the following review helpful. Excellent By Scott McDonald This book is more than a history of the movements of a Civil War Regiment that successfully defended East Texas from Federal invasion. Through detailed narratives the author delves into the background of the soldiers, their motivations, and brings to life their true stories of starvation, forced marches, diseases, extreme weather, horror of battle and loss of life. This compelling book is backed up by solid research and is generously punctuated with quotes from the men involved, maps and photographs. A real must read for any history buff.

1 of 1 people found the following review helpful. A look at my Great Grandfather Carter's Life in Sires and Sons By Mary Ellen Braneff I really enjoyed this book. I became acquainted with the author on Face Book. My great grandfather Cpl. John Harmon Carter was in the 22nd. Texas Infantry and I have the original of a letter that he wrote to his family in Dec. 1862 while stationed in Camp Nelson, Ark. I shared this letter with the author along with other stories about the hardships and many deaths they had suffered. Mr. Wardlaw has done a wonderful job of giving these wonderful men and their families life again and helping us understand the horror and pain they went through. Thank you so much. As a note my great grandfather was born in Tennessee and came to East Texas about 1850 with his parents, siblings and his small daughter in Oxen driven wagons. They settled in Gilmer, Upshur County, TX.

1 of 1 people found the following review helpful. I am the great, great granddaughter of William Ratliff featured on page ... By Melissa M. I am the great, great granddaughter of William Ratliff featured on page 77 of this book. I enjoyed going back in time with my grandfather's unit to walk in their shoes and "experience" what my grandfather might have gone through. The book was well researched. He laid a foundation of basic Texas history and set up the major players that we followed all through the book. What some people would call dry historical facts were given life through genealogies, letters and diaries bringing the unit to life in a way that could place you there with them. It's nice to know specifically what my grandfather might have endured compared to general knowledge of the Civil War. Thank you for the work you put into it Trevor, I for one really appreciate it.

See all 11 customer reviews... Sires and Sons: The Story of Hubbard's Regiment, by Trevor P. Wardlaw


Sires and Sons: The Story of Hubbard's Regiment, by Trevor P. Wardlaw PDF
Sires and Sons: The Story of Hubbard's Regiment, by Trevor P. Wardlaw iBooks
Sires and Sons: The Story of Hubbard's Regiment, by Trevor P. Wardlaw ePub
Sires and Sons: The Story of Hubbard's Regiment, by Trevor P. Wardlaw rtf
Sires and Sons: The Story of Hubbard's Regiment, by Trevor P. Wardlaw AZW
Sires and Sons: The Story of Hubbard's Regiment, by Trevor P. Wardlaw Kindle

Sires and Sons: The Story of Hubbard's Regiment, by Trevor P. Wardlaw

Sires and Sons: The Story of Hubbard's Regiment, by Trevor P. Wardlaw

Sires and Sons: The Story of Hubbard's Regiment, by Trevor P. Wardlaw
Sires and Sons: The Story of Hubbard's Regiment, by Trevor P. Wardlaw

Rabu, 25 Desember 2013

Bayou Jesus, by M.G. Miller

Bayou Jesus, by M.G. Miller

By downloading this soft file book Bayou Jesus, By M.G. Miller in the on the internet link download, you remain in the 1st step right to do. This site truly provides you simplicity of ways to get the very best publication, from ideal seller to the brand-new launched book. You could find much more publications in this site by checking out every web link that we offer. One of the collections, Bayou Jesus, By M.G. Miller is one of the very best collections to market. So, the first you obtain it, the very first you will obtain all positive regarding this e-book Bayou Jesus, By M.G. Miller

Bayou Jesus, by M.G. Miller

Bayou Jesus, by M.G. Miller



Bayou Jesus, by M.G. Miller

Best Ebook PDF Bayou Jesus, by M.G. Miller

If Jesus came to us today, who would he be? Louisiana in the first half of the twentieth century convulses between old and new, antebellum and modern. Zassy, a sharecropper coming to adulthood finds what she thinks is love with a traveling Bible salesman, but ends up with real love from a son she is sure is a blessing from God. Samson, master of a failing plantation, returns from war with dreams of a resurrected South, only to find his wife sinking into alcoholism from his abuse. The daughter born to them grows up to rebel against everything he stands for. And at the heart of the story, Frank Potter, Zassy's son, struggles through the web of greed and lust to find his way to the God who looms above the world like a judging father. The lines of all these lives weave together into the threads of love and service that form the tapestry of religion and asks us to find the Christ in all of us. Entrancing, altruistic and shocking, the Jesus of Miller's bayou is a gritty meditation on the changing times, and will haunt readers' memories long after others fade.

Bayou Jesus, by M.G. Miller

  • Published on: 2015-05-12
  • Original language: English
  • Number of items: 1
  • Dimensions: 9.02" h x .63" w x 5.98" l, 1.02 pounds
  • Binding: Hardcover
  • 210 pages
Bayou Jesus, by M.G. Miller

Review "...Miller is in a class of artisans whose prose will someday sit on august library shelves alongside Steinbeck and Faulkner..." --Dusty Richards, author of Noble’s Way"...Miller is indeed a rare talent. His words are exquisite, compassionate, and reveal a depth of understanding..." --Velda Brotherton, author of Wandering in the Shadows of Time

About the Author M.G. Miller is the author of numerous award-winning Southern Gothic novels ranging from literary fiction to psychological thrillers and horror. A former editor for a national magazine of speculative fiction, Miller lives in Arkansas.


Bayou Jesus, by M.G. Miller

Where to Download Bayou Jesus, by M.G. Miller

Most helpful customer reviews

9 of 10 people found the following review helpful. When things get bad, who is your Saviour? By Jack Dalton Where to begin?In the Jim Crow South, where black people still felt like slaves?In the War times, when women died every day, wondering?In the Depression, when a human being will grasp at anything, regardless of color?At the embryo of Civil Rights, when white men will grasp at anything to maintain their power over coloreds and women?Or the one who might dare stand up against it, regardless of the price?Perhaps there is no place to truly begin. There is too much amazing stuff here.And yet, while you may be overwhelmed by the universal human emotion of Bayou Jesus, you are getting a very true education of a very real time, but through the eyes of people history tries to forget, has forgotten.Enter Frank Potter. Young. Black. Bastard child. But to whom everyone is strangely drawn to.Circumstance means he's nothing special. But true "special" requires no particular circumstance.And yet, I promise, despite the utterly devastating conclusion, you'll realize this isn't a story about Frank Potter, a possibly holy black man in the bayou.This is the painfully human story of seeking, not salvation, but redemption.After all, all the main characters are either black or female, and this was written by a young white man.When you're done, you'll realize it takes a hearty soul to read it . . .And then you'll remember who wrote it.And realize, there is no color in the soul of a human being that wants to speak the truth.Just the truth.Thank you, M G Miller for searching your soul, and history, to write this.

8 of 9 people found the following review helpful. The Color of a Voice By Jan Morrill Since the release of the book and movie, The Help, there has been much discussion of whether or not a writer can capture the voice of a character outside of his race or gender. M.G. Miller answers that question in his book Bayou Jesus. His portrayal of Miss Zassy, Frank, Jolene and Alice -- each outside of his gender and/or race -- is gripping, not only in the dialect he writes, but also in the internalization of thoughts and feelings. But then, aren't so many of our thoughts and feelings universal, regardless of gender or race?

1 of 1 people found the following review helpful. Bayou Jesus is a visceral and darkly beautiful novel so powerfully written that it is impossible to ... By Parris Afton Bonds Bayou Jesus is a visceral and darkly beautiful novel so powerfully written that it is impossible to turn from, even in the moments when I cringed most for the vividly depicted characters. Sazzy, around whom the drama revolves, is as familiar to us as our own skins ~ and, thus, offers each of us a glimpse of redemption by the story's last page. Richly reminiscent of Tennessee Williams, Bayou Jesus will stay with you long after you have finished the novel.

See all 39 customer reviews... Bayou Jesus, by M.G. Miller


Bayou Jesus, by M.G. Miller PDF
Bayou Jesus, by M.G. Miller iBooks
Bayou Jesus, by M.G. Miller ePub
Bayou Jesus, by M.G. Miller rtf
Bayou Jesus, by M.G. Miller AZW
Bayou Jesus, by M.G. Miller Kindle

Bayou Jesus, by M.G. Miller

Bayou Jesus, by M.G. Miller

Bayou Jesus, by M.G. Miller
Bayou Jesus, by M.G. Miller

Rabu, 18 Desember 2013

How the Gringos Stole Tequila: The Modern Age of Mexico's Most Traditional Spirit,

How the Gringos Stole Tequila: The Modern Age of Mexico's Most Traditional Spirit, by Chantal Martineau

How if there is a website that enables you to hunt for referred book How The Gringos Stole Tequila: The Modern Age Of Mexico's Most Traditional Spirit, By Chantal Martineau from throughout the globe author? Instantly, the site will be unbelievable finished. A lot of book collections can be found. All will be so very easy without complex thing to move from website to website to obtain guide How The Gringos Stole Tequila: The Modern Age Of Mexico's Most Traditional Spirit, By Chantal Martineau really wanted. This is the site that will certainly provide you those expectations. By following this website you could get great deals numbers of book How The Gringos Stole Tequila: The Modern Age Of Mexico's Most Traditional Spirit, By Chantal Martineau compilations from versions types of writer and also publisher preferred in this world. The book such as How The Gringos Stole Tequila: The Modern Age Of Mexico's Most Traditional Spirit, By Chantal Martineau as well as others can be acquired by clicking great on link download.

How the Gringos Stole Tequila: The Modern Age of Mexico's Most Traditional Spirit, by Chantal Martineau

How the Gringos Stole Tequila: The Modern Age of Mexico's Most Traditional Spirit, by Chantal Martineau



How the Gringos Stole Tequila: The Modern Age of Mexico's Most Traditional Spirit, by Chantal Martineau

Free Ebook How the Gringos Stole Tequila: The Modern Age of Mexico's Most Traditional Spirit, by Chantal Martineau

Once little more than party fuel, tequila has graduated to the status of fine sipping spirit. How the Gringos Stole Tequila traces the spirit's evolution in America from frat-house firewater to luxury good. But there's more to the story than tequila as upmarket drinking trend. Author Chantal Martineau spent several years immersing herself in the world of tequila -- traveling to visit distillers and agave farmers in Mexico, meeting and tasting with leading experts and mixologists around the United States, and interviewing academics on either side of the border who have studied the spirit.The result is a book that offers readers a glimpse into the social history and ongoing impact of this one-of-a-kind drink. It addresses issues surrounding the sustainability of the limited resource that is agave, the preservation of traditional production methods, and the agave advocacy movement that has grown up alongside the spirit's swelling popularity. In addition to discussing the culture and politics of Mexico's most popular export, this book also takes readers on a colorful tour of the country's Tequila Trail, as well as introducing them to the mother of tequila: mezcal.

How the Gringos Stole Tequila: The Modern Age of Mexico's Most Traditional Spirit, by Chantal Martineau

  • Amazon Sales Rank: #354523 in Books
  • Brand: Martineau, Chantal
  • Published on: 2015-05-01
  • Original language: English
  • Number of items: 1
  • Dimensions: 9.00" h x .90" w x 6.00" l, .0 pounds
  • Binding: Hardcover
  • 304 pages
How the Gringos Stole Tequila: The Modern Age of Mexico's Most Traditional Spirit, by Chantal Martineau

Review "A phenomenal book -- probably one of the smartest books about a spirit I've ever read." --The Toronto Star "A rich story... engaging." -- The Wall Street JournalBest of 2015 cocktail (and spirits) books: "'How the Gringos Stole Tequila' [is] a lively exploration of the heritage, culture, practices and politics that shape Mexico's most famous export. Martineau introduces producers using traditional agricultural and distillation methods, shows readers why they're worth preserving, and outlines the challenges facing anyone concerned with the quality and sustainability of tequila, mezcal and other agave spirits." -- The Kansas City Star "Martineau journeys through Mexico interviewing producers of the agave-based spirits tequila and mescal. She's dismayed that international beverage distributors now design and market Mexico's signature alcoholic drinks and that techniques of mass production too often sacrifice integrity and authenticity." -- Foreign Affairs "Martineau argues convincingly that good tequila resembles wine more than it does its fellow liquors. She writes of agave plantations as if they are vineyards, with variations in climate, slope, soil, and moisture resulting in variations in the plants that are, in turn, discernible in the distilled product. She co-opts the precious French word terroir and applies it to her subject with no intended loss of dignity." -- The Los Angeles Review of Books "Martineau makes her nonfiction debut with this thoroughly researched study of what appears to be a growing trend in the spirit world: the rise of tequila from a low-end frat-party tipple to a high-end connoisseur's sipping drink." —Kirkus Reviews“The perfect read to accompany your tequila, mezcal, or pulque—all drinks made from the mature agave, the spiky Mexican succulent with a heart that can become distilled gold. Chantal Martineau has written a compelling travelogue, tasting guide, business analysis, and ecological primer that firmly places tequila and its cousins as worthy spirits beyond cheap college margarita drunks.”—Mark Pendergrast, author of Uncommon Grounds: The History of Coffee and How It Transformed Our World“Chantal Martineau ties our fate as Americans with the ecosystem of the agave, which is threatened, like our foodways, by shortsighted industrialization and corporate greed. The struggle is complicated as it relates to the tequila-loving gringo, and as one, I am deeply grateful for the way Martineau has portrayed it.” —Jim Meehan, author of The PDT Cocktail Book“This wonderfully written book illuminates a part of the spirits industry that even the most diehard aficionado might not know about.”—Tom Acitelli, author of The Audacity of Hops: The History of America’s Craft Beer Revolution“Martineau is an adept guide, charming and deeply knowledgeable, to the intricate and fascinating world of agave-based spirits. With passion and authority, How the Gringos Stole Tequila argues that tequila and mezcal are not cheap firewater, but rather richly cultural and potentially threatened products worthy of connoisseurship.”—Bryce T. Bauer, author of Gentlemen Bootleggers: The True Story of Templeton Rye, Prohibition, and a Small Town in Cahoots“For anyone curious but largely uneducated about agave spirits, Ms. Martineau makes a fine instructor.” —Wall Street Journal“Martineau’s book is an excellent introduction to tequila’s long history and complicated evolution over the last 15 years…”  —Distiller “a lively exploration of the heritage, culture, practices and politics that shape Mexico’s most famous export. Martineau introduces producers using traditional agricultural and distillation methods, shows readers why they’re worth preserving, and outlines the challenges facing anyone concerned with the quality and sustainability of tequila, mezcal and other agave spirits.” —Kansas City Star

About the Author Chantal Martineau is a Montreal native now based in New York who writes about wine, spirits, food, travel and culture. Her writing (sometimes accompanied by her own photography) has been published in Saveur, Afar, The Atlantic, Redbook, Islands, The Guardian, The Huffington Post, The Walrus, The Globe and Mail and more. She appeared in the Travel Channel's Confessions of a Travel Writer and is the author of How the Gringos Stole Tequila: The Modern Age of Mexico's Most Traditional Spirit.


How the Gringos Stole Tequila: The Modern Age of Mexico's Most Traditional Spirit, by Chantal Martineau

Where to Download How the Gringos Stole Tequila: The Modern Age of Mexico's Most Traditional Spirit, by Chantal Martineau

Most helpful customer reviews

2 of 3 people found the following review helpful. One Star By Amazon Customer Bad research about tequila and the industry.

0 of 0 people found the following review helpful. Great historical book with good, useful information By C. Soberman Interesting book for an American living in Mexico. I always preferred Mezcal - now I know why. We spent a night in the town of Tequila a couple of years ago. Pure Disney. Would never return.

0 of 0 people found the following review helpful. Read while sipping..... By madasi Informative, enlightening, added to and expanded my knowledge of all things agave. Highly recommend.

See all 8 customer reviews... How the Gringos Stole Tequila: The Modern Age of Mexico's Most Traditional Spirit, by Chantal Martineau


How the Gringos Stole Tequila: The Modern Age of Mexico's Most Traditional Spirit, by Chantal Martineau PDF
How the Gringos Stole Tequila: The Modern Age of Mexico's Most Traditional Spirit, by Chantal Martineau iBooks
How the Gringos Stole Tequila: The Modern Age of Mexico's Most Traditional Spirit, by Chantal Martineau ePub
How the Gringos Stole Tequila: The Modern Age of Mexico's Most Traditional Spirit, by Chantal Martineau rtf
How the Gringos Stole Tequila: The Modern Age of Mexico's Most Traditional Spirit, by Chantal Martineau AZW
How the Gringos Stole Tequila: The Modern Age of Mexico's Most Traditional Spirit, by Chantal Martineau Kindle

How the Gringos Stole Tequila: The Modern Age of Mexico's Most Traditional Spirit, by Chantal Martineau

How the Gringos Stole Tequila: The Modern Age of Mexico's Most Traditional Spirit, by Chantal Martineau

How the Gringos Stole Tequila: The Modern Age of Mexico's Most Traditional Spirit, by Chantal Martineau
How the Gringos Stole Tequila: The Modern Age of Mexico's Most Traditional Spirit, by Chantal Martineau

From the combo of knowledge and activities, an individual can improve their skill and also capability. It will lead them to live and function much better. This is why, the pupils, employees, and even employers need to have reading habit for publications. Any sort of publication will certainly offer particular knowledge to take all perks. This is exactly what this informs you. It will certainly include more knowledge of you to life and also work better. , Try it and also show it.





Ebook PDF Online





Where to Download




PDF
iBooks
ePub
rtf
AZW
Kindle

Selasa, 17 Desember 2013

The Seleukid Empire of Antiochus III (223-187 BC), by John D. Grainger

The Seleukid Empire of Antiochus III (223-187 BC), by John D. Grainger

Beginning with visiting this site, you have attempted to start nurturing checking out a publication The Seleukid Empire Of Antiochus III (223-187 BC), By John D. Grainger This is specialized site that offer hundreds compilations of publications The Seleukid Empire Of Antiochus III (223-187 BC), By John D. Grainger from lots resources. So, you won't be bored anymore to select guide. Besides, if you likewise have no time at all to browse guide The Seleukid Empire Of Antiochus III (223-187 BC), By John D. Grainger, merely sit when you remain in office as well as open up the web browser. You can discover this The Seleukid Empire Of Antiochus III (223-187 BC), By John D. Grainger inn this web site by hooking up to the net.

The Seleukid Empire of Antiochus III (223-187 BC), by John D. Grainger

The Seleukid Empire of Antiochus III (223-187 BC), by John D. Grainger



The Seleukid Empire of Antiochus III (223-187 BC), by John D. Grainger

Best Ebook PDF The Seleukid Empire of Antiochus III (223-187 BC), by John D. Grainger

The second volume in John Grainger's history of the Seleukid Empire is devoted to the reign of Antiochus III. Too often remembered only as the man who lost to the Romans at Magnesia, Antiochus is here revealed as one of the most powerful and capable rulers of the age. Having emerged from civil war in 223 as the sole survivor of the Seleukid dynasty, he shouldered the burdens of a weakened and divided realm. Though defeated by Egypt in the Fourth Syrian War, he gradually restored full control over the empire. His great Eastern campaign took Macedonian arms back to India for the first time since Alexander's day and, returning west, he went on to conquer Thrace and finally wrest Syria from Ptolemaic control. Then came intervention in Greece and the clash with Rome leading to the defeat at Magnesia and the restrictive Peace of Apamea. Despite this, Antiochus remained ambitious, campaigning in the East again; when he died in 187 BC the empire was still one of the most powerful states in the world.

The Seleukid Empire of Antiochus III (223-187 BC), by John D. Grainger

  • Amazon Sales Rank: #469149 in Books
  • Brand: Grainger, John D.
  • Published on: 2015-05-19
  • Original language: English
  • Number of items: 1
  • Dimensions: 9.30" h x 1.00" w x 6.30" l, 1.20 pounds
  • Binding: Hardcover
  • 240 pages
The Seleukid Empire of Antiochus III (223-187 BC), by John D. Grainger

About the Author John D. Grainger is a respected historian with a particular reputation for military subjects. His recent publications include Cromwell Against the Scots (Boydell Press, 2005) and The Battle of Yorktown (Tuckwell Press, 1997).


The Seleukid Empire of Antiochus III (223-187 BC), by John D. Grainger

Where to Download The Seleukid Empire of Antiochus III (223-187 BC), by John D. Grainger

Most helpful customer reviews

7 of 7 people found the following review helpful. Still very good, but not quite as good By JPS This is the second volume in John Grainger's history of the Seleucid Empire and it is entirely centred on the (long) reign of Antiochus III, perhaps the best documented Seleucid reign.For once, the “marketing blurb” of the cover page (and which figures on Amazon’s sites) reflects some of the book’s contents rather well. Antiochus is indeed “too often remembered only as the man who lost to the Romans at Magnesia” and this book does show him “as one of the most powerful and capable rulers of the age.” However, it also shows that his defeat against the Romans was not a disaster, that the war was no “walk-over” for the Romans, and that they almost lost at Magnesia.The chapters on the Antiochus’ War against Rome are probably among the very best of the book and they largely draw from the author’s more scholarly publication on the same topic. The description of the politics and how the premises of the war were rewritten by pro-Roman authors afterwards are particularly well shown. The mistakes of the Seleucid King are also well analysed.The rise of Antiochus to power, or rather how he had to fight to keep his throne and reconquer his Empire province by province, is also well told. Particularly well told are the parts related to the Fourth and Fifth “Syrian Wars” against the Ptolemy rivals and where, again, the author has published a much more complete by more scholarly and terribly expensive book. Also well-described is the re-conquest of Asia Minor which draws on a number of works, such as John Ma’s, but also some of the John Grainger’s himself. I was less impressed by the sections on Antiochus’ “Anabasis”, as it has been called, that is his multi-year tour and expedition with his army in the Upper Satrapies to consolidate the northern (Armenia and Cappadocia), eastern rand north eastern frontiers. While good, I found these pieces perhaps less impressive, although, to be fair, they are also those that are the least documented.Another strongpoint which comes across throughout the book shows to what extent it was a major and hugely difficult task to hold together the Empire. This required an indefatigable King rushing from one front to another and preferably backed by a younger heir who would keep control of the area where the senior ruler was not at the time. As with his predecessors, this was what Antiochus achieved first with Antiochus the Younger, who fought with him during the Fifth Syrian War, and then with Seleukos, his eventual successor, who took part in the war against the Romans in Asia.Particularly interesting is the author’s assessment that, despite losing the war against the Romans, Antiochus III’s Seleucid Empire at his death was certainly better off than when he became King. A related point was to show that while losing Thrace and Asia Minor was certainly a blow, it also removed a major source of distraction. The loss of Asia Minor meant that the Seleucid kings were longer embroiled in the multiple conflicts pitting its various smaller states and cities against each other. It was balanced, and probably ever more than balanced, by the re-acquisition of all of the rich Coele Syria and the destruction of the overseas Ptolemaic Empire and the weakening of the this perennial rival.Despite its many qualities, however, I did have a few issues with this title which I did not find it quite as could as the previous volume, nor quite as clear as Michael Taylor’s biography on Antiochus III.One is that I had the impression that I was reading a watered down and simplified version because at least some of the chapters are condensed versions of more scholarly but also more complete, works. This shows in a number of cases throughout the book but particularly so when discussing campaigns and the Seleucid army. This is a topic where the author has heavily relied upon and borrowed from Bar Kochva’s superb study. While acknowledging this through his notes (although, oddly enough, Bar Kochvas’s book does not manage to make it to the bibliography!), John Grainger does depart from it in a number of respects but never really gets to discuss these differences.One example is the author’s choice to stick to a chronological narrative throughout the book. The consequence is the absence of thorough discussion on the Seleucid army (its recruitment, composition and performances, in particular), of the Empire’s resources and of its government. There are bits and pieces on these three topics, and references to other more detailed books, but these are scattered throughout the book. This leads to some odd and unexplained statements at times, such as the one where, according to the author, the kingdom’s core field army was limited to some 35000 with this number seeming to be plucked out of thin air.The absence of a more detailed discussion on numbers at Magnesia also gives the impression that the Roman and allied forces were larger than that of the Seleucid King whose light troops seems to have been omitted. John Grainger does make a very valid point in underlining that Livy’s assertion about the almost total loss of the Seleucid expeditionary force that accompanied the King to Greece is ludicrous and a gross exaggeration. Several thousand – and perhaps as many as half or two-thirds of the slightly more than ten thousand - must have made their way back to Asia Minor with the King in what was an organised evacuation rather than a free for all escape. Also, while the author mentions that the Aetolians (Antiochus’ allies in the war in Greece against the Romans) were able to provide perhaps more than ten thousand mercenaries to the Ptolemaic King against Antiochus some ten years before, he never gets to really explain how and why they were only able to field four thousand against the Romans at Thermopylae.There also seems to be missing or incomplete statements or even wrong ones when discussing some of the battles. The author does successfully explain the discrepancy in numbers, and the relatively small size of the Seleucid force at Thermopylae - some ten to eleven thousand plus about four thousand Aetolians facing more than twenty five thousand Roman and allies who were expecting further reinforcements. He does not really explain why the Hellenistic monarch chose to fight this battle when the odds where so unfavourable and what he expected to gain by a successful holding action. The description of the subsequent discussions and the naval war to obtain control of the Straits so that the Roman forces to cross to Asia are well shown, and so is the fact that Antiochus evacuated Thrace to concentrate all his forces.Also well shown is the fact that it is Antiochus who had the really innovative tactics and that these almost succeeded in crushing the Romans at Magnesia. However they failed, largely thanks to Eumenes action on the Roman right flank so that John Grainger is in a way correct to state that, at Magnesia, it is the latter that was instrumental in the Roman victory rather than the Roman general and his Roman and Italian allies. However, contrary to a couple of strange statements, Antiochus’ tactics also failed in part. Grainger does show that the intention was a dual cavalry assault, but one of these, on the Seleucid failed (and was not a success, contrary to the author’s assertion) while the other, spearheaded by the King himself, broke through a Roman legion but then attacked the Roman camp and failed to rally and attack the Roman battle line from the rear and flanks. It is this failure to rally and control his victorious cavalry that cost the Hellenistic monarch the battle, more than anything else, just as it had cost him the battle over a quarter of a century before when something similar happened to him at Raphia against the Ptolemaic army.For the reasons above, and if this had been possible, I would have rated this book somewhere in between three and half and four stars. Since it is not, I will assign it four stars

2 of 2 people found the following review helpful. A slightly imperfect addition to the story of the Seleukid Empire By Dominicus Once again John D. Grainger has written an exceptional book highlighting one of the most overlooked empires in history and one of it's greatest rulers who is widely misunderstood today thanks to ancient Roman propaganda and the all-too-eager willingness of modern day historians and readers to take the works of ancient writers at face value.My only disappointments with this piece of work is that Mr. Grainger didn't go into more detail regarding the inner workings of the Seleukid Empire during this time period. Topics such as how he reinvigorated the empire's economy after the Third Syrian War and Molon's rebellion, how the satrapies were reorganized following these conflicts or improved upon and how Antiochus III improved and reformed the Seleukid army with the introduction of the kataphracts and horse archers (the latter of which in admittedly limited quantity).Despite those critiques, this is an excellent book that will go a long way to enlightening people about the Seleukid Empire and to slowly restore some of Antiochus the Great's unjustly tarnished legacy.

0 of 1 people found the following review helpful. terrific read, I was there and knew ANTIOCHUS111 personally ... By z9z9 terrific read, I was there and knew ANTIOCHUS111 personally so I can tell you this book is spot on!! Z9Z9

See all 3 customer reviews... The Seleukid Empire of Antiochus III (223-187 BC), by John D. Grainger


The Seleukid Empire of Antiochus III (223-187 BC), by John D. Grainger PDF
The Seleukid Empire of Antiochus III (223-187 BC), by John D. Grainger iBooks
The Seleukid Empire of Antiochus III (223-187 BC), by John D. Grainger ePub
The Seleukid Empire of Antiochus III (223-187 BC), by John D. Grainger rtf
The Seleukid Empire of Antiochus III (223-187 BC), by John D. Grainger AZW
The Seleukid Empire of Antiochus III (223-187 BC), by John D. Grainger Kindle

The Seleukid Empire of Antiochus III (223-187 BC), by John D. Grainger

The Seleukid Empire of Antiochus III (223-187 BC), by John D. Grainger

The Seleukid Empire of Antiochus III (223-187 BC), by John D. Grainger
The Seleukid Empire of Antiochus III (223-187 BC), by John D. Grainger

Rabu, 11 Desember 2013

No Behind, by Louise Parker Kelley

No Behind, by Louise Parker Kelley

Simply connect to the net to gain this book No Behind, By Louise Parker Kelley This is why we mean you to utilize and utilize the industrialized innovation. Checking out book does not suggest to bring the published No Behind, By Louise Parker Kelley Established innovation has allowed you to review just the soft data of the book No Behind, By Louise Parker Kelley It is exact same. You could not need to go as well as get traditionally in searching the book No Behind, By Louise Parker Kelley You may not have adequate time to spend, may you? This is why we give you the best method to obtain guide No Behind, By Louise Parker Kelley now!

No Behind, by Louise Parker Kelley

No Behind, by Louise Parker Kelley



No Behind, by Louise Parker Kelley

Free Ebook PDF No Behind, by Louise Parker Kelley

An extraordinary 4th grader survives an epidemic in quarantine with the rest of her school. She uses her newfound courage and resourcefulness to declare independence and challenge the mindless tyranny of standardized testing. This is a work of fiction. All incidents, dialogue and characters are drawn from the author's imagination and are not be construed as real. Any resemblance to real persons, living or dead, is purely coincidental.

No Behind, by Louise Parker Kelley

  • Published on: 2015-05-20
  • Released on: 2015-05-20
  • Format: Kindle eBook
No Behind, by Louise Parker Kelley


No Behind, by Louise Parker Kelley

Where to Download No Behind, by Louise Parker Kelley

Most helpful customer reviews

6 of 8 people found the following review helpful. Louise Parker Kelley's brilliant fiction about educational testing gets it so right! By Carolivia Herron This book does not use the likenesses of people. Louise is just a very good writer of fiction. The story has come from her imagination. The images on the cover have come from the imagination of the illustrator. Louise Parker Kelley's "No Behind" is a brilliant fictionalization of the frustration that can result from the wrong application of the "No Child Left Behind" directive. I particularly love Kelley presentation of inner dialogue as the child endures so much misunderstanding.

0 of 0 people found the following review helpful. A fine read! By Kathleen A. Baxter This is an extensive look at the life of a very inteligent, extremely creative young immigrant who decides to rebel against the testing which is destroying her education-and the talents and creativity of her teachers.

1 of 2 people found the following review helpful. Super read! By Susie Welsh What a dystopia we are creating here in the US -- both current education policies, as well as the fictional epidemic. Shades of ebola! And only a 4th grader is clear-eyed enough to see it? This is really a book for adults. Super read!

See all 7 customer reviews... No Behind, by Louise Parker Kelley


No Behind, by Louise Parker Kelley PDF
No Behind, by Louise Parker Kelley iBooks
No Behind, by Louise Parker Kelley ePub
No Behind, by Louise Parker Kelley rtf
No Behind, by Louise Parker Kelley AZW
No Behind, by Louise Parker Kelley Kindle

No Behind, by Louise Parker Kelley

No Behind, by Louise Parker Kelley

No Behind, by Louise Parker Kelley
No Behind, by Louise Parker Kelley

Selasa, 10 Desember 2013

Building the Empire State: Political Economy in the Early Republic (American Business, Politics, and Society),

Building the Empire State: Political Economy in the Early Republic (American Business, Politics, and Society), by Brian Phillips Murphy

So, when you require quickly that book Building The Empire State: Political Economy In The Early Republic (American Business, Politics, And Society), By Brian Phillips Murphy, it does not need to wait for some days to obtain guide Building The Empire State: Political Economy In The Early Republic (American Business, Politics, And Society), By Brian Phillips Murphy You could directly obtain the book to save in your device. Even you love reading this Building The Empire State: Political Economy In The Early Republic (American Business, Politics, And Society), By Brian Phillips Murphy almost everywhere you have time, you could appreciate it to check out Building The Empire State: Political Economy In The Early Republic (American Business, Politics, And Society), By Brian Phillips Murphy It is surely handy for you that want to obtain the much more valuable time for reading. Why don't you spend 5 minutes as well as invest little cash to obtain guide Building The Empire State: Political Economy In The Early Republic (American Business, Politics, And Society), By Brian Phillips Murphy here? Never ever let the extra point quits you.

Building the Empire State: Political Economy in the Early Republic (American Business, Politics, and Society), by Brian Phillips Murphy

Building the Empire State: Political Economy in the Early Republic (American Business, Politics, and Society), by Brian Phillips Murphy



Building the Empire State: Political Economy in the Early Republic (American Business, Politics, and Society), by Brian Phillips Murphy

Ebook PDF Building the Empire State: Political Economy in the Early Republic (American Business, Politics, and Society), by Brian Phillips Murphy

Building the Empire State examines the origins of American capitalism by tracing how and why business corporations were first introduced into the economy of the early republic. Brian Phillips Murphy follows the collaborations between political leaders and a group of unelected political entrepreneurs, including Robert R. Livingston and Alexander Hamilton, who persuaded legislative powers to grant monopolies corporate status in order to finance and manage civic institutions. Murphy shows how American capitalism grew out of the convergence of political and economic interests, wherein political culture was shaped by business strategies and institutions as much as the reverse.

Focusing on the state of New York, a onetime mercantile colony that became home to the first American banks, utilities, canals, and transportation infrastructure projects, Building the Empire State surveys the changing institutional ecology during the first five decades following the American Revolution. Through sustained attention to the Manhattan Company, the steamboat monopoly, the Erie Canal, and the New York & Erie Railroad, Murphy traces the ways entrepreneurs marshaled political and financial capital to sway legislators to support their private plans and interests. By playing a central role in the creation and regulation of institutions that facilitated private commercial transactions, New York State's political officials created formal and informal precedents for the political economy throughout the northeastern United States and toward the expanding westward frontier. The political, economic, and legal consequences organizing the marketplace in this way continue to be felt in the vast influence and privileged position held by corporations in the present day.

Building the Empire State: Political Economy in the Early Republic (American Business, Politics, and Society), by Brian Phillips Murphy

  • Amazon Sales Rank: #1008673 in Books
  • Published on: 2015-05-07
  • Original language: English
  • Number of items: 1
  • Dimensions: 9.10" h x 1.20" w x 6.00" l,
  • Binding: Hardcover
  • 304 pages
Building the Empire State: Political Economy in the Early Republic (American Business, Politics, and Society), by Brian Phillips Murphy

Review

"In Building the Empire State, Brian Murphy deftly revisits the founding of New York State, in the process revising our understanding of how the political economy of the early republic operated in practice. Rather than a strict separation between the public obligations of the state and the private interests of for-profit corporations, Murphy finds a much more integrated, reciprocal relationship that organically emerged from the experiences of the late colonial and Revolutionary periods. His fresh approach and sophisticated argument make a significant contribution to several fields, including political history, business history, and the history of capitalism more broadly."—Sharon Murphy, Providence College

About the Author Brian Phillips Murphy teaches history at Baruch College.

Excerpt. © Reprinted by permission. All rights reserved.

IntroductionStrength in Structure

One late spring day in Manhattan in 1784, Robert Robert Livingston Jr. did something he and his peers did nearly every day of their adult lives: he sat down, pulled out a sheaf of paper, and began scribbling.

For the past seven years, the 37-year-old aristocrat had been New York State's chancellor, one of its top judicial officials. The position had been created under a new state constitution New York adopted in 1777 after the separation from Great Britain. Livingston coauthored that document and all but inherited the newly created post; his late father, Robert R. "Judge" Livingston Sr. had also been a prominent jurist and politician in colonial New York.

Politics was one of the Livingston family's businesses, and Robert Junior had long been busy at the center of the politics of Revolution. In 1775 he became a delegate to the Continental Congress in Philadelphia, and in 1776 he was one-fifth of the Committee of Five tasked with drawing up a Declaration of Independence. He returned to New York to frame that state's 1777 constitution, was named the state's chancellor by a provisional governing body, and left again in 1781 to serve as his country's first secretary of foreign affairs, its senior-most diplomatic official.

But now all of that was in the past.

As the national capital ambled from Philadelphia to Princeton to Annapolis, the center of its politics drifted further and further from Livingston's reach and from New York itself, where the Livingston name—one that had dominated colonial politics for a century—seemed to be at a nadir. In the New York legislature, some of the Revolution's leaders, whom the chancellor had labeled "warm & hotheaded Whigs," seemed determined to permanently keep men like him from wielding anything like his former power. Having come under fire for being an absentee state officeholder, Livingston resigned his foreign affairs post in 1783 and returned home to mend ties in New York. He spent months battling the allegation by the Whigs that he had in fact vacated the office of chancellor once he began serving in Congress. Even after that controversy quieted, a smaller contingent of legislators pestered the chancellor by proposing to cut his £400 salary in half while debating a bill that gave raises to the governor and every other judge in the state.

Livingston quietly began plotting his recovery by falling back on a playbook his family had (successfully) used for generations: rebuilding his political capital by rebuilding his financial capital. As a political entrepreneur descended from several generations of political entrepreneurs—people who sought to translate their influence and connections into sources of income and opportunity—Livingston was used to living in a state where the official apparatus of government was his collaborative and encouraging partner, aiding his enterprises and giving a boost to his personal ambitions and those he had for the civic well-being of New York City. The animating energy of colonial government had long come from collaborations between official entities and local private interests. In Livingston's mind, the propriety of that relationship had in no way been discredited by the Revolution. Restoring those pre-Revolutionary practices would favor Livingston's family and others with capital to invest and influence to exercise, and for the next thirty years Robert Livingston planned and profited from political-economy practices he helped set.

During the fall of 1783, Livingston began spending money and political capital to reestablish both the city of New York and his footing within it. He began enticing friends and associates to join him in buying houses and estates vacated during the war or abandoned by Tory Loyalists who had fled the country. Livingston had already invested £2,800 in such properties and was seeking a credit line of £8,000 to plunge even deeper into the venture. At the same time, he was assembling a portfolio of associates to cofound a so-called land bank where such real estate holdings could be mortgaged for paper money.

What frustrated Robert Livingston enough to decry the city's "notorious" greed in early 1784 was that the official apparatus of New York's government—both its state legislature and the city corporation governing New York City through an appointed mayor and an elected board of aldermen—was not reciprocating. As he read newspaper articles about other states' willingness to use incorporation grants to harness civic energy and mobilize private capital, Livingston saw New York failing to support the ambitions he and other New Yorkers harbored for their city and state. His bid for a bank charter was stalled in the state legislature, and New York's municipal government seemed to be immobilized and subject to the whims of petty entrenched interests looking to preserve their own narrow privileges at the expense of others.

Pouring his angst onto four long, narrow ledger-sized sheets of laid cotton paper—the kind lawyers used for formal court filings and Livingston used for everything—the chancellor fumed that "since the peace, a rage has prevailed in the neighboring states for corporations" that "annex ideas of utility to them." But in New York "we have not been so fortunate." Although "the fire" of 1776 "left open a door for improvement" and history had provided London's 1666 singe as a model for what an active and ambitious city government could do under such circumstances, New Yorkers refused to "[do] things themselves or [avail] themselves of the spirit of enterprise that the war has left with us."

According to the chancellor, New York City's government had become incapable of following through on even basic tasks. New Yorkers had gotten good at "[projecting] useful schemes for posterity to carry into effect," the chancellor wrote. Streets that should have been repaired for "the health & embellishment of the town" had instead become "the abode of verb & excuses." The city corporation had planned to plant trees that would re-create the "cool & shady walks" New Yorkers had enjoyed before the war. With the planting season nearly over, however, the chancellor marveled, "[N]o step has yet been taken." "Even this shadowy improvement," he predicted, "is liable to cheat our hopes." A "scheme," Livingston reflected, "is extinguished with the same rapidity that it was embraced." "Half a dozen old women" could arrest work on a project by merely "scold[ing] . . . the profanity" entailed in "[exposing] dark recesses of stone street . . . to publick view."

Livingston thought city leaders had been cowed into inaction by incumbent interests and entrenched monopolists who were "too powerful for the rest of the citizens" to defeat. The influence of these forces, Livingston believed, distorted the city's political economy and marketplace to the detriment of consumer-citizens. Spoiled bread flour that should have been "held up to public view" by a regime of city-appointed inspectors was instead being sold to unsuspecting buyers, all to keep "the customs of our ancestors, encourage luxury, and discourage . . . the sale of unmarketable flour." An abundance of fresh water that could have provided "comfortable refreshments" to residents while "guard[ing] us against the alarming ravages of fire" was instead unavailable—all because the proprietors of a spring-fed well called the "Tea-Water Pump" stood in the way. "It is a notorious fact," he wrote, "that the greed of this city is worse than that of any other place upon the continent." "[A]las we have little hope to expect," Livingston sighed, that such an improvement "will be crowned with [success] while there are tea-water men, and tea-water women & tea-water children" insisting they alone had gained in 1757 the permanent and exclusive right to supply the city with water for all time. As long as their government refused to challenge the status quo, New Yorkers would be left with no choice than to be "tormented from seeing the cup glide by them after it was brought to their chins," destined "neither to eat or drink like other folk." "It is our common reproach to want bread and water" even though "the means of obtaining both are in our power." The only public project New Yorkers could truly be proud of, Livingston bitterly concluded, was the city's decades-old gallows. They were "distinguished," he noted, by their strength, and were "in the word[s] of Hamlet's grave digger, built stronger than the carpenter or mason."

In his lifetime, Robert Livingston sent thousands of letters and published nearly a dozen widely read essays. This, however, was not one of them.

There is no indication that Livingston returned to this essay or revised it or that it was ever sent—to anyone. One of Livingston's biographers linked it to another letter sent to New York City mayor James Duane—the husband of one of the chancellor's cousins. But that missive is mocking and mischievous in tone, clearly intended to irk the mayor. That letter was a bridge-burner that flayed both the city's political leadership and the public alike and was originally written for publication in a newspaper. It was an essay written at a moment when, in a bitter letter to his friend John Jay, the chancellor said he had "concluded my political career."

Livingston might have simply wanted to spare his family embarrassment or shield himself from this momentary departure from rhetorical elegance. However, his statement to Jay about having "concluded" his political life cries out for further scrutiny. By what measure could Livingston credibly claim to be exiting politics? It certainly would have surprised New York State's legal and political community to learn that their sitting chancellor considered himself retired, particularly when his daily actions and ongoing engagements plainly contradicted this statement. As a man raised in the innermost circles of New York politics during British dominion, Livingston was clearly irritated and even disturbed by his state's postwar politics during these first years of American independence now called the Critical Period.

The Revolution fundamentally challenged the colonial status quo, empowering people who wanted to deny former colonial aristocrats the chance to return to their positions at the top of the new nation's political and socioeconomic ladders. Some ideological imperatives, therefore, demanded that Robert Livingston feel frustrated in 1784, and a cadre of state legislators stood ready to make his political life as difficult as possible. Livingston's reaction was evidence of just how unfamiliar, at least to him, this new environment had become. He remained determined, however, to turn his lands, money, connections, and family name into sources of profit and influence—not as an aristocrat but as a political entrepreneur.

Yet the chancellor was all too aware that not every New Yorker with capital was committed to the same agenda. When the chancellor railed against the "notorious fact" of the "greed of [New York City]," he was drawing a contrast between himself and others who sought privileges in the political marketplace. Livingston saw himself as a positive force in his country's politics. Profit was just one of several reasons he was interested in banking and real estate investing, activities that he viewed as constructive contributions toward the commercial success and political stability of his state. The marketplace regulations and interventions he desired—flour inspections, freshwater supplies, street paving, tree planting—had long been permissible and even definitional duties of municipal governments that had been constituted under a royal charter, operated within common law, and rechartered following independence.

Although localities, states, and the developing national confederation had adopted formal articles and constitutions, the nation's actual day-to-day governing habits—its applied political economy—were still up for grabs at this moment in American history. In New York, as in the nation, the proper extent of the state's mixed economy of public-private enterprises had hardly been debated, let alone defined. The ideological imperatives of the Revolution were competing with familiar practices of pre-Revolutionary governance, and although some lawmakers wanted to further exploit their opportunity to effect social and economic change, others sought to settle the Revolution as soon as possible. The state government, Livingston told Robert Morris, was "weak, unsettled." The monopoly-holders of the Tea-Water Pump and deceitful flour merchants were fine with that and with exploiting a lack of competition in the political marketplace to wring profits from an already anemic economy. To Livingston, their greed was parasitic, and the city government's inaction amounted to a betrayal of the Revolution's "spirit of enterprise" that was to be "encourage[d] . . . in others." Livingston's essay, therefore, did not merely address a personal agenda; the larger question hovering over his words and the country as a whole in 1784 was: What happens now?

Political economy is a well-defined term in American history: the way that states and governments ordered the economy and operated within the marketplace. As much as is known about it in theory, however, less is understood about the interactions among legal and extralegal voluntary associations, chartered and informal institutions, and political officials with backgrounds and futures in commercial and transportation development. But these ground-level machinations, complex and often messy, are what political economy is once it is operationalized.

Building the Empire State surveys and samples the changing institutional ecology of New York State during the first five decades following independence, a period my fellow historians call the early republic, by following a community of entrepreneurs like Robert R. Livingston, and their enterprises. New York was a onetime mercantile colony that, as a state, became home to the first bank incorporated after the Revolution (the Bank of New-York), utilities, canals, railroads, and other internal improvement companies, as well as the country's most powerful steamboat monopoly and the largest public works project of the early republic: the Erie Canal. Within this geographical context, this book investigates political economy in practice: I ask how ideas and ideologies gave way to actions and policies, and I explore the political, economic, and legal consequences of chartering particular institutions and organizing the marketplace in certain ways. In this period, New York's state government was busy opening avenues for profit and influence to its citizens, prompting them to organize and mobilize as economic interests in order to take advantage of these opportunities. By asserting authority in creating and regulating institutions that facilitated and intermediated private commercial transactions throughout the northeastern United States and toward the expanding westward frontier, New York's political officials set the formal rules of the game and defined the informal norms of behavior in one of the nation's busiest commercial centers and largest economies, demonstrating that "the state" was one of the primary agents of change in the early republic's economy.

But although early American states were important in this era, they were hardly omnipotent. Operating within a layered federal regime of divided and shared sovereignties; early state governments lacked the jurisdictional authority, fiscal imagination, and public consent to directly undertake comprehensive revenue-intensive programs of nation-building. To compensate, lawmakers tapped the rule-making powers that were implicit in American statehood and constitution-making in order to reward private coalitions' capital-formation abilities with formal institutional structures and legal privileges. Legal tools that had been the legacy of British imperial rule—charters for business corporations and banks, and monopoly grants for technology and transportation, for example—were repurposed by American lawmakers to serve the republic's domestic needs. By restructuring and selectively bestowing these useful instrumentalities on favored groups, New York State political leaders created an economy of political opportunity that linked private ambition to the public weal.

Flinging the doors of statehouse chambers open to petitioners eager to gain legal privileges and realize exclusive profits resurrected the familiar pre-Revolutionary practice of engaging private entities to finance, construct, and manage civic institutions and ostensibly public assets. The landscape of political opportunity in the early republic was dominated by an economy of influence in which financial capital readily purchased political and regulatory power; this incentivized coalition-building and rewarded legislative skill. It also empowered public officials to steer private capital toward building a financial and transportation infrastructure capable of encouraging further commercial ambition and hastening economic development. Government therefore got things done by deliberately bestowing public authority on individuals and institutions in order to tap private capital and channel self-interest toward public goods and civic ends. As a consequence, legislators willingly—and in some cases inadvertently—sustained the influence of a cadre of unelected political actors whose stature flowed from their personal access to private capital: political entrepreneurs.

Once they were organized into legally sanctioned and formalized partnerships and corporations, these out-of-doors unelected operatives and political entrepreneurs began curating their interests; they recruited supporters from the ranks of elected officials to deepen and widen their ties to voters. Though far from uniform or unanimous, support for politically oriented entrepreneurs among a growing interlocking directorate of citizen-shareholders and corporate directors frustrated the practical day-to-day efforts of constitution-writers and lawmakers to collar unelected individuals' and associations' capabilities to bend the vast power of the state's rule-making regulatory apparatus in their favor. Successful political entrepreneurs actively interested people in their enterprises by building networks of credit that offered access to debt and capital, by transforming the transactional relationship between modest citizen-shareholder investors and high-born corporate officers into durable long-term political alliances, and by constructing a partisan infrastructure to bring institutional discipline to the state's official sources of political authority. In the new nation's political economy, therefore, the energies of government, subordinate political institutions, and political parties were all fueled in large measure by extra-legislative, out-of-doors mobilizations undertaken for economic and material reasons.

For elected officials and appointees, catering to constituents' material interests was no distraction; it was the daily grind of the business of governing. Perusing the journals of legislative houses and statute books makes clear that such work consumed a great deal of attention from New York's political class in the early republic. Across a spectrum of letters of affection and agitation, it is clear that there was a consensus position shared among a broad swath of political entrepreneurs in the early republic—George and DeWitt Clinton, Robert R. Livingston, Robert Fulton, Aaron Burr, and Alexander Hamilton, accompanied by a large and wide cohort of less-studied figures—that a chief purpose of politics and government was to advance citizens' material interests and promote a commercial agenda. Creating a dynamic marketplace required the interposition of state power, and in the view of this cohort, government was supposed to be actively aiding the ambitions of the ambitious; for them, the controversy most often concerned whose enterprising plans merited support.

Although it is not surprising that capital and corporations exercised political power in the early republic (as they still do) or that political actors responded to them (ditto), it was not a given that the institutional ecology of New York State would evolve to revolve around the community of political entrepreneurs at the center of these enterprises. These experiments in privilege and monopoly were tests of the public's patience for private enterprises entrusted with exclusive rights to execute a public mission. And the political intensity of American corporations' early origins—particularly banks and transportation enterprises—helps explain why contemporaries and historians alike frequently cast a skeptical eye toward their emergence in the early republic.

This story is, after all, a paradox: corporations morphed from being objects of suspicion and symbols of monarchy in the late eighteenth century to being the dominant tool for capital formation and business organization by the middle of the nineteenth century.

From the seemingly antibank, anticorporate, and antimonopoly political-economy rhetoric of the 1780s, an interwoven set of incorporated banks emerged in the United States that financed a set of semi-exclusive transportation initiatives. It is easy to explain this development as an enlargement of privileges among an already privileged cadre of self-dealing political leaders who succumbed to corruption and materialist temptations. Certainly the metaphysical efforts of political-economy theorists to sort out distinctions between public and private spheres of action was undermined by the state's adoption of corporations and monopoly grants to run mixed-economy enterprises. Most efforts to use politics to restrain the influence of capital in early America were struggles that seem destined to fail.

Yet the subtle, often unspoken assumption underlying many histories of the politics and political economy of the early republic is that angst concerning corporations and concentrations of capital was widespread across thirteen states' legislatures and the public. Through the ideological prisms of republicanism and liberalism, our unfortunate present-day predicament can seem avoidable and even accidental. The shorthand narrative goes something like this: starting with the creation of incorporated banks after the Revolution, capital was unleashed with the emergence of rapacious railroads, a "Market Revolution," and a more laissez-faire marketplace that came to be dominated by trusts and monopolies in the Gilded Age. Economic histories of the period often rely on the same narrative to reach a strikingly different conclusion: one celebrating laissez-faire as the demise of the anticapitalist radicalism of the American Revolution and the blossoming of a more nearly perfect and correct set of institutional arrangements between the public and private sectors.

Historians have identified a spectrum of "good founders" who presciently recognized that corporations, monopolies, and other institutions for capital formation and the aggregation of influence had the potential to endanger the institutions of government and civil society; some believed they had no place in the nation's political economy, while others thought they could be unleashed only after first being mastered. A cadre of state legislators in Pennsylvania held firm in opposing all incorporated banks and trying to repeal an existing bank's charter, while in Massachusetts lawmakers sought to house-train corporations by tinkering with the details and complexities of corporate charter language. These histories of politics and political economy look to the founding generation for the answers they formulated to questions concerning how interests were to be managed in the young republic, poring over warning signs our forebears missed in this "lost moment" when history could have unfolded in a different way.

But this is precisely why context is key.

Early American lawmakers considering petitions for legal privileges needed to look no further than the 1773 Tea Act for an example of how a corporation's shareholders could sway parliamentarians' votes, distorting an empire's political economy and propelling its colonies into open rebellion. The East India Company, however, was a unique institution without a North American equivalent.

By contrast, American historians writing in the twentieth and twenty-first centuries approach this subject with their own particular constellation of references. Whenever most people are asked what the word corporation means to them—whether they are detached scholars and journalists, interested policy makers and politicos, or students considering the question for the first time—they conjure answers that reference the signposts of our era. They do not think of the British East India Company or its favored position in the eighteenth-century tea market but settle their brains on the twenty-first-century companies they interact with on a regular basis. To live in the United States today is to live in a nation where well-organized private interests dominate the defense, health-care, banking and finance, and media and publishing industries, as well as science, all manner of transportation, and much of the everyday commerce of nearly 300 million citizens.

Despite the sticky web of complication woven by this system as it was practiced, the vocabulary we use in our present political discourse continues to insist that somewhere, deep under layers of institutions, money, motives, and grey shades of legality, an identifiable line once existed that demarcated the boundary between What Is Public and What Is Private.

This assumption lies at the heart of decades of state legislative and congressional lawmaking and United States Supreme Court litigation aiming to limit the influence of corporations and wealthy individuals on elections and policy making. But even after drawing and redrawing limitations on who can participate in a campaign, when and how much they can contribute, and in what places and spaces candidates and lawmakers can solicit support, little seems to have been redeemed. Despite the creation of a Federal Election Commission (FEC) in 1974; the Court's 1976 decision in Buckley v. Valeo; the adoption of the Bipartisan Campaign Reform Act (McCain-Feingold) in 2002; internal efforts by congressional ethics committees; audits by the executive branch; state governments' oversight and policing of agencies, officials, and legislators; and citizens' activities in monitoring disclosure reports, filing Freedom of Information Act (FOIA) requests, and signing Public Interest Research Group (PIRG) petitions, the applied political economy of the United States remains inherently muddled.

The federal regime's regulatory apparatus often appears to be deliberately designed to be captured by the industries being monitored. Many sectors of the U.S. economy are dominated by just a handful of corporations, often operating as duopolies or monopolies. And although these firms are said to be part of the free and private marketplace, their positions are protected and their power is undeniably felt throughout the public sector. In the formal exercise of policy making, rule-making, lawmaking, and the crafting and enforcement of administrative regulations, and in the informal but highly lucrative economy of influence sustained by lobbying, deal-making, political fundraising, and seasonal electioneering, any lines that might separate public and private spheres and markets in our era seem blurred beyond recognition. The most fundamental, basic tasks of the modern American state—"to insure domestic Tranquility, provide for the common defense, promote the general Welfare"—are today executed within the mixed economy of socialized risks, private rewards, public funds, public oversight, and private profit.

Judges, policy makers, and even government activists do not seem able to carve out distinct public and private spheres in thinking about how America's political economy should work, largely because reforms fail to take full notice of how that political economy works in practice.

What if there was no lost moment? What if, instead of swinging into action as an afterthought to restrain a politics driven by ideology (or honor or culture) in the early republic—think of James Madison's Federalist No. 51—material interests were instead at the very heart of post-Revolutionary and post-Constitutional Convention politics, used to both excite and temper competing imperatives? If true, we could then view the "emergence" of corporations and economic institutions as a continuation of past practices adjusted to fit new political arrangements.

Much rhetoric of the American Revolution redefined civic space by drawing boundaries around influence and power. Pamphleteers, Continental congressmen, and minutemen all evinced hostility to accumulations of wealth, concentrations of political authority in a single individual or among a court of collaborators, and the conflation of personal wealth with a right-to-rule that was common in pre-Revolutionary times. The idea that a man's political power emanated from his person, was legitimated by his property, and automatically elevated him to a stature sufficient to merit an office might not have been explicitly annihilated by the Revolution, but it was certainly disrupted by challenges to authority, aristocracy, and deference. Although wealth itself was not abolished, it was nevertheless divested of any implied grant of authority. Inheritances and marriages were no longer investiture ceremonies. The Revolution formally decoupled fitness for office from accidents of birth, marriage, and fortune once the legitimate source of government authority was relocated from the King, his ministers, and his imperial dependents to the sovereign people and their duly elected deputies in legislatures, councils, and congresses.

Yet this legacy was fundamentally jeopardized by the building of an institutional matrix of state-chartered enterprises responsible for igniting both financial and transportation "revolutions" in this era. To fund and run these corporations, monopolies, and other projects, lawmakers politically empowered a particular class of individuals: people with capital. Political entrepreneurs were people without boundaries, not at all self-conscious or deeply conflicted about using political leverage to gain economic advantages and deploying capital to win political disputes. They embodied in their person powers that were, in theory, reserved only for public bodies and to be dispensed only by popular consent in the new democratic republic. This form of authority nevertheless radiated throughout the institutions of New York's economic life. Participating in the marketplace as a corporate director or shareholder; as a licensee of a state monopoly or partner in a state-sanctioned venture; as a holder and defender of a federal patent; as a bank depositor or borrower; as a bond holder in federal, state, or corporate securities; or even as a single signer among hundreds on a petition on behalf of a canal, railroad, or other project sent to the state capital were all avenues to participate in the state's political and civic life, demolishing any pretense of there being boundaries between the two.

Ordinarily we think of this process as one of exploitation or regulatory capture that occurs when private firms gain sway over their public regulators. But what we learn in Building the Empire State is that no such coup d'état happened; it was never necessary. American capitalism instead grew out of collaborations between political and economic interests—a dynamic in which business strategies and institutions were shaped by political strategies and institutions, and vice versa. In the case of Robert Livingston, self-interested and civic motives could be harmonious; he had no qualms about positioning himself and his investments for a favorable outcome if his larger civic plans became a reality or in gaining personal political power by circumventing the electoral process to become the principal of a commercially and financially influential extra-legislative institution. For him, no meaningful distinction existed between public authority and private capital. Politics existed, in part, to ensure that the two were intertwined; Livingston and his peers built their coalitions of investors with an eye toward translating money into political leverage.

Although business, banking, and corporate histories are often indexed by the formal names of firms and institutions, the process of actually creating a political economy is personal and contingent. This is not a study that rests comfortably in the gallery of a legislature to rehash debates over a banking bill, nor does it dwell in casebooks or libraries. Thanks to almost two decades of brilliant interdisciplinary studies into political culture and a push to move "beyond the Founders," we know that politics is not confined to recorded debates at the federal level. If we want to know what happened and how things really worked, we need to recover what happened out of sight in conference rooms and out of doors in the streets of the states and localities that composed the federal union. At each layer of the regime, officials were regularly besieged with proposals and petitions from people promising access to financial capital. But awarding privileges to these applicants was not a blind process favoring just anyone with money; legislators did not turn to strangers to build the republic. Instead, successful petitioners were more likely to be coalitions and partnerships that deliberately blended financial capital, political capital, and human capital in the form of technological, engineering, or other forms of specialized expertise. At the friction point where private initiative met public authority, well-crafted coalitions were represented by lobbyists, current and former legislators, officials, and opinion leaders who, in turn, seduced other lawmakers with personal assurances that a coalition had the know-how and capital to plan, execute, and complete a project, delivering a public good in return for a publicly given privilege and an opportunity for private profit. Therefore, the very process of creating a financial and transportation infrastructure in the early republic had structural incentives that favored a particular species of business coalition—one assembled with political savvy—because the winnowing process used by legislators to cull through stacks of petitions demanded no less.

As Robert Livingston observed in 1784, officials charged with policy making in the new republic—city aldermen, state legislators, judges, governors and their small circles of advisers—all were more responsive to organized interests than airy notions of the public good or specific demands backed by a disorganized—if unified—"popular" will. For lawmakers and government officials "the public good" was not a self-evident vision; even at rare moments of apparent consensus, opposing economic interests could use their institutional advantages to thwart policies intended to serve that public, civic good. Therefore the legal privileges conferred on particular groups long ago and under a now-deposed regime had given them an institutional permanence that was undeniably difficult to overcome. Being so well established in the political marketplace allowed these groups to amplify their wishes—however narrow and selfish—giving them an outsized voice in policy making. Moreover, the state's inaction reinforced this institutional asymmetry by discouraging the formation of countervailing rival institutions and coalitions.

In the emerging American political system, therefore, the pre-Revolutionary habit of attending to organized, mobilized, and institutionalized interests had remained in place. Government responded to pressure from established interests; it was irrelevant whether those interests were discredited so long as they faced no meaningful opposition. In pondering the failures of the early 1780s, Robert Livingston had come to appreciate the important role that the institutionalization of political interests played in creating engaged and competent public and mixed-economy enterprises. For Livingston, the novelty of this situation was that it was an institutional problem he could not change by leaning on his aristocratic name or his immense inherited land holdings. The sellers of spoiled bread flour and "Tea-Water men" had enfeebled the city government's capacity to address matters of public health and commercial regulation, not because those ideas lacked merit or because the city lacked the legal authority to assert its police powers in those areas but because no countervailing interests existed to agitate for those measures. The chancellor and others, therefore, could pine all they wanted for more energetic public authorities and more civically oriented projects, but these plans would always be at risk of being defeated so long as advocates were unorganized and unstructured. Being interested was not the same as being an interest, let alone an institution. A hungrier and thirstier population might be unhappy, but unless they were mobilized and organized, they were unlikely to see the government change its course. Electing a slate of more favorable candidates to the state legislature or the city's board of aldermen would not provide a cure because the underlying problem was a lopsided institutional ecosystem.

With this realization Livingston had discovered a loophole in the radicalism of the American Revolution: a small number of people could multiply their impact by organizing themselves into associations and institutions with permanence and influence. For this reason, Robert Livingston, who hailed from one of the nation's most wealthy and aristocratic families, had been at the apex of Revolutionary politics, and claimed to have "concluded my political career," decided in early 1784 to write, circulate, and submit a petition asking the state legislature to create a corporation. Livingston saw commerce, and banking in particular, as a useful tool for revolutionary settlement—the process of bringing the Revolution to a close now that the war was over. He believed commerce could mend the frayed relationship between the city and state's revolutionary Patriots—Whigs both mild and "hot-headed"—and those former Tory Loyalists who decided to remain in America and cast their lot with the new republic. If Livingston could channel influence and money toward the common goal of repairing and rebuilding the city's physical plant, he could help New York City reemerge from the conflict as a commercial center with a vigorous mixed economy and population of Tories and Patriots who were each stakeholders in the city's success. Meanwhile, he could personally profit from his investments while gaining leverage over and influence within the city and state's political economy by installing himself and select like-minded associates at the head of what would become the state's most influential financial institution. In the months following a Revolution against imperial abuses, unaccountable power, and monarchical tyranny, New York's chancellor had decided how he would maximize his influence in the new nation's political system: he would become a banker.

In creating a market, therefore, the state had defined what was at stake in political competition. By simply responding to interests, the state encouraged the formation of interests that would marshal financial, human, and technical capital on behalf of proposed projects. In addition, lawmakers prodded aspiring citizen-shareholders to organize plans; identify, recruit, and mobilize supporters: consolidate investor capital: and circulate petitions later unfurled in lobbies and cloakrooms in Manhattan, Albany, and Washington. Once legislators had decided to engage outside interests in the act of state formation, the boundary between politics and capital became as thin as the paper petitions for those charters and grants.

Embracing the complexities and context of these narratives is crucial; the instinct to search for clean hands and pure intentions is little different from the temptation to impose ahistorical "public" and "private" categories on mixed-economy institutions. The early republic's applied political economy was consciously manipulated by its participants in a way that militates against such neatness. Once the first shovel of canal dirt or turnpike mud was turned over by a worker paid in paper banknotes that had been carried upriver aboard a privately owned state-licensed steamboat and unloaded on a private pier at a public port, any bright categorical lines we imagine had long been trampled underfoot. Similarly, divisions between partisanship and supposedly apolitical business relationships crumbled once people began identifying themselves as Federalists, Republicans, or Whigs, for personal financial reasons, and switched affiliations if such a move would deliver advantages in business, credit, legal privileges, or political appointments. Even during the Critical Period and "Revolution of 1800," when ideological commitments reached high-water marks, political leaders were busy constructing legislative and electoral majorities with promises of public patronage, private favoritism, and competitive advantages in commerce and business. Taken together, these statutes, petitions, and journals; the debates they ignited; and the institutions they spawned are the clearest articulation of what Americans expected from their government and envisioned for their political economy in this era.

The key to understanding the political economy of the early American republic is to appreciate that there was strength in numbers, so too was there strength in structure. Government was now under the control of a more popular politics; the key to gaining leverage in the city and state's political economy lay in mobilizing the people who were the constituent members of the sovereign state of New York's body politic. Like it or not, the most durable and useful legal tool to accomplish that turned out to be the corporation, a development the legacy of which we continue to wrestle with today.

Case Studies in Empire Building

The chapters in this book are chronologically organized as case studies, examining how the business strategies of political entrepreneurs were directly related to the political structures of the state and responsive to the wishes of lawmakers.

Chapter 1 details the introduction of finance capital and commercial banking into the un-banked mercantile community of New York City. Propelled by newly won state sovereignty and seeking competitive advantages in politics, policy making, and commerce, several separate cohorts of elite New Yorkers tried to found incorporated banks in 1784. When only one of those proposed banks, the Bank of New-York, opened its doors and did so without the state's blessing, it nevertheless gained legitimacy by rooting itself in the state's institutional ecosystem as a lender to the state and municipal government and a bulwark against the incursions of a federal bank.

Chapter 2 examines the founding of the Northern and Western Inland Lock Navigation Companies, two Albany-area canal companies chartered in the early 1790s to connect the Hudson River to Lake Erie and Lake Champlain. Both companies failed and were seen as cautionary precursors to the Erie Canal.

Chapter 3 looks at how a clever cabal of elites manipulated the corporate chartering process to launch a bank from within a water utility, called the Manhattan Company, in 1799. For nearly a decade, the Bank of New-York used its financial leverage to sway political favor and block new entrants from opening rival banks until Aaron Burr and other New York Democratic-Republicans seized an opportunity to open their own bank. Amid the controversy, partisans and bankers confronted the political implications of partisan corporations and the propriety of using credit as a tool in electoral competition.

Chapter 4 examines the complicated political economy of monopoly rights in the early republic during the beginning of the nineteenth century. Even more so than the corporation, the embrace of monopoly privileges by early American states was a continuation of an imperial practice that was unquestionably monarchical: giving one person or association a long-term exclusive right to a route, waterway, structure, type of business, or stream of revenue. A paradox emerged in the republic's use of the privilege: a successful monopoly inspired legal and political challenges, forcing its proprietors to be open to partnerships with would-be rivals. In the case of the steamboat, state legal protections were ultimately more useful in maintaining a monopoly's viability than any federal patent protection for technology.

Chapter 5 considers the implications of New York lawmakers' 1817 decision to directly manage and publicly finance the Erie Canal, which fundamentally changed the relationship between the state government and its maturing institutional ecosystem. The diminishing appeal of exclusive privileges led to a fundamental reorientation in state policy with the public mobilization on behalf of the Erie Canal and legislative wrangling over how it would be financed. Although it is thought of as a "public" project and one of the first of its kind, beneath that veneer it was a hybrid—a desirable investment among wide slices of the electorate who included proprietors of incorporated financial institutions and land speculators who stood to benefit from its operation, and a civic project that legislators and merchants realized would bring the western United States into the close orbit of New York, creating the conditions for the city and state to become the commercial epicenter of the eastern seaboard.


Building the Empire State: Political Economy in the Early Republic (American Business, Politics, and Society), by Brian Phillips Murphy

Where to Download Building the Empire State: Political Economy in the Early Republic (American Business, Politics, and Society), by Brian Phillips Murphy

Most helpful customer reviews

1 of 2 people found the following review helpful. Great read! Very informative and well-written By Joan Murphy Great read! Very informative and well-written.

See all 1 customer reviews... Building the Empire State: Political Economy in the Early Republic (American Business, Politics, and Society), by Brian Phillips Murphy


Building the Empire State: Political Economy in the Early Republic (American Business, Politics, and Society), by Brian Phillips Murphy PDF
Building the Empire State: Political Economy in the Early Republic (American Business, Politics, and Society), by Brian Phillips Murphy iBooks
Building the Empire State: Political Economy in the Early Republic (American Business, Politics, and Society), by Brian Phillips Murphy ePub
Building the Empire State: Political Economy in the Early Republic (American Business, Politics, and Society), by Brian Phillips Murphy rtf
Building the Empire State: Political Economy in the Early Republic (American Business, Politics, and Society), by Brian Phillips Murphy AZW
Building the Empire State: Political Economy in the Early Republic (American Business, Politics, and Society), by Brian Phillips Murphy Kindle

Building the Empire State: Political Economy in the Early Republic (American Business, Politics, and Society), by Brian Phillips Murphy

Building the Empire State: Political Economy in the Early Republic (American Business, Politics, and Society), by Brian Phillips Murphy

Building the Empire State: Political Economy in the Early Republic (American Business, Politics, and Society), by Brian Phillips Murphy
Building the Empire State: Political Economy in the Early Republic (American Business, Politics, and Society), by Brian Phillips Murphy